|
164 |
AU |
: |
Andersen S |
TI |
: |
Some aspects of the economics of tuberculosis in India.
|
SO |
: |
Tuberculosis and Chest Disease Workers Conference,
18th, Bangalore, India, 16-19 Jan 1962, p. 204-212. |
DT |
: |
CP |
AB |
: |
1The present paper describes certain economic aspects
of TB in India, but does not attempt to combine them in a model.
The estimated direct costs (beds, clinics, BCG campaign, drugs,
private practitioners, after-care, social welfare etc. and research,
training and administration) and indirect costs (disablement, premature
death) of TB services of all kinds in India, based on known number
of physical units multiplied by estimated average cost, have been
calculated. These calculations demonstrated that the TB control
programme which the NTP was proposing, was not substantially more
expensive to the nation than existing TB services. It was concluded
that a far higher government share would be economical and that
district programmes utilising and promoting the development of basic,
GHS would also be economical.
|
KEYWORDS: SOCIAL CHANGE; HEALTH ECONOMICS; INDIA. |
165 |
AU |
: |
Nagpaul DR & Vishwanath MK |
TI |
: |
Economics of health. |
SO |
: |
Tuberculosis and Chest Diseases Workers Conference,
22nd, Hyderabad, India, 3-6 Feb 1967, p. 277-300. |
DT |
: |
CP |
AB |
: |
Health has been defined as the state of perfect
physical, social and mental well-being which is somewhat of an abstract
definition. In this paper, economics of health is measured through
economics of sickness. Because sickness is experienced, it can be
measured and it inflicts physical, social and economic sufferings.
In a community, economic prosperity is directly dependent on quantum
of sickness and its prevention by health services. A sociological
enquiry into the part played by disease in the socio-economic development
of society was made by carrying out a study in two village population
groups. The Social Investigators of NTI made deep, probing questions
to elicit presence of symptoms, action taken by them, money spent
on treatment and the loss of wages. In the first study, observation-participation
technique was adopted. The investigators lived in the village for
four months. In the second study, 20% households of those 22 villages
which participated earlier in an epidemiological survey conducted
by NTI, were interviewed.
Findings of the two studies are combined and presented.
Illnesses were classified into major and minor on the basis of clinical
severity and the duration of symptoms. In both the studies, 60%
of all persons were asymptomatic during 2 months prior to the interview.
About 18% had one minor illness, 13% had major illness and only
3% had one major and one minor illness. The quantum of multiple
disease (3 or more) occurring in one person was less than 2%. Only
20% of living man-days were spent as sick man-days. The average
annual loss on account of health reasons per family has been estimated
to be Rs.90/- and Rs.15/- per capita. The overall economic loss
due to sickness, direct and indirect amounted to 3% of the per capita
income in the poorer groups of villages and 6% in the economically
more favourably placed villages. The material available here strongly
suggests that the sizes of households will not have much influence
over the sickness in the community. Another significant feature
of this study was the phenomenon of substitution within the family
whenever the wage earner could not go to work. The evidence examined
in this paper suggests that the actual economic loss is only 1/3rd
of the calculated loss. It also suggests that the overall cost of
sickness to the individuals and family is far less than what is
normally calculated and is influenced by the money available in
the household.
|
KEYWORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; SOCIAL COST; INDIA. |
166 |
AU |
: |
Banerji D |
TI |
: |
Health economics in developing countries. |
SO |
: |
Tuberculosis and Chest Diseases Workers Conference,
22nd, Hyderabad, India, 3-6 Feb 1967, p. 301-311. |
DT |
: |
CP |
AB |
: |
It is now widely recognised that investment in
health fields contributes to economic growth of countries by stimulating
growth in human capital formation and by preventing
economic loss due to sickness, disability, premature death and cost
of treatment. An integrated plan, in which investment in certain
key areas in health field is made side by side with investment in
similar areas in other social and economic fields, is essential
for reversing the vicious circle of poverty and sickness in developing
countries. Health economists will have to work in close collaboration
with social planners in other fields in order to develop certain
common units for measuring health and other social and economic
problems and to identify those areas for investment in health fields
which have considerable bearing on social and economic development.
|
KEYWORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; SOCIOMETRY; INDIA. |
167 |
AU |
: |
Sen AS & Basu RN |
TI |
: |
Economics of health-the cost of tuberculosis. |
SO |
: |
INDIAN J TB 1972, 19, 144-158. |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
In a study of the cost of TB in India, a direct
cost of Rs. 29.68 crores annually has been estimated. The morbidity
and mortality losses have been quantified taking into account the
urban and rural population separately. The data on mortality in
rural areas is very meager and is not available according to age
and sex. This, and the expected working life for premature mortality
have been calculated by the application of statistical methods.
The morbidity loss has been estimated at Rs. 288.4 crores and the
mortality losses at Rs. 420.41 crores at 4 percent deduction and
Rs. 304.96 crores at 10 percent deduction.
|
KEYWORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; SOCIAL COST; SOCIAL WELFARE;
INDIA. |
169 |
AU |
: |
Dholakia R |
TI |
: |
The potential economic benefits of the DOTS strategy
against TB in India edited by Almeida J |
SO |
: |
WHO/TB/96.218 |
DT |
: |
WHO Technical Information Series |
AB |
: |
The DOTS strategy has been demonstrated to overcome
most of the short-comings of self-administered chemotherapy such
as low cure rates, high relapse and fatality rates, drug resistance
etc. There are several benefits from successful application of the
DOTS strategy. The objective of this study was to estimate the direct
economic benefits by the reduction in the prevalence of TB and deaths
averted on account of DOTS. The methodology adopted has been the
comparison of the two scenario with DOTS and without
DOTS and deriving the benefits and calculating the discounted
value of the contributions of the DOTS by applying the discount
rates ranging from 5% to 16%. The estimates are generated by using
the marginal productivity of labour and the deaths averted by DOTS
among future workers in each age-sex-area category. The discounted
value of the contributions of the future workers among the deaths
averted in one year due to DOTS, the remaining years of their productive
life are considered as the economic benefits of the deaths averted.
The total benefits due to DOTS have been estimated as % of G.D.P.
in 1993-94 and annualized benefits due to DOTS as % of G.D.P. The
potential benefits are derived by using the most reliable 1993 estimates
from survey of causes of deaths.
The potential benefits of successful DOTS in India
are divided into two broad categories (I) Pure social welfare increasing
effects of DOTS which do not generate direct tangible economic benefits.
These would include reduced suffering of TB patients, quick and
sure cure from the disease, lives saved, disability reduced for
dependents and non-workers suffering from TB, the poverty alleviation,
the psychic benefits of living in a more healthy way. (ii) Direct
tangible economic benefits by improving the efficiency and productivity
due to reduction in prevalence of disease and deaths and release
of the hospital beds by averting hospitalization of TB patients.
The method of calculation is based on the estimates
of population for the base year 1993-94 by age-sex-area as well
as of the workers and sectors. Aggregative macro-economic studies
and estimates of productivity differentials are used to calculate
rural/urban, adult/child, young adult/old adult and male/female
workers output gains. These are applied to two groups with
DOTS and without DOTS and the benefits in the
improvements likely to occur with DOTS have been estimated.
The benefits are based on twin optimistic assumptions:
a) DOTS will succeed in tackling pulmonary TB in India (b) DOTS
will reach about 90% of TB patients with full instantaneous coverage.
It is envisaged to implement DOTS in a phased manner over a few
years. As per the findings of the analysis the potential economic
benefits of DOTS to the Indian economy is estimated to be around
4% of GDP in real terms or US $ 8.3 billion during 1993-94. The
economy gets a return of more than 16% per annum. Since the present
value of all future costs attributable to DOTS is likely to be less
than 4% of GDP, DOTS can effectively help step up Indias future
economic growth. Phasing in of DOTS over time reduces value of the
economic benefits. The longer the period of phasing, the lower is
the discounted value of the benefits. Even with 10 years of phasing
and 16% of discount rate all future benefits of DOTS turn out to
be 2.1% of G.D.P. Projected incremental costs to the government
for successful DOTS implementation throughout India are of the order
of US $ 200 million per year, compared to the tangible economic
benefits of at least US $ 750 million per year exceeding by several
folds of the financial costs.
|
KEY WORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; DOTS; ECONOMIC BENEFITS;
INDIA |
170 |
AU |
: |
Croft RA & Croft RP |
TI |
: |
Expenditure and loss of income incurred by tuberculosis
patients before reaching effective treatment in Bangladesh |
SO |
: |
INT J TB & LUNG DIS 1998, 2, 252-54 |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
This small study undertook to assess the economic
consequences of developing TB among patients presenting to the TB
clinic run by the Danish Bangladesh Leprosy Mission in NW Bangladesh.
The loss of income resulting from the illness, and the actual expenditure
incurred by medicines and doctors fees before registration
for treatment, were estimated and totaled for 21 patients serially
registered at the clinic. The results showed a mean financial loss
to the patient of US$ 245 - an exorbitant sum for a village Bangladeshi.
Perhaps economic deprivation suffered by TB patients could be used
as a measure of success of the programme.
|
KEY WORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; BANGLADESH |
171 |
AU |
: |
Chadha VK, Preetish S V & Sanjay Singh |
TI |
: |
Tuberculosis control and economic issues |
SO |
: |
NTI BULLETIN 1999, 35, 3-7 |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
The health of its people is reflected in the economy
of a nation healthy people produce healthy economies. It
is unfortunate that in our country the effects of ill health on
economy have not been fully appreciated. The burden imposed on individuals,
families and the community by disease like TB contains an economic
dimension. TB extracts costs invariably in an economic sense
al all levels of the society, either directly through expenditure
incurred in providing health and social care and support, or indirectly
in terms of lost opportunities such as loss of employment. Other
intangible costs include the anguish and anxiety experienced by
the patients and their families. The havoc wrought by TB on individuals,
families, whole communities and economies is enormous. Economic
issues related to the problem of TB and its control are discussed
in detail in the paper.
|
KEY WORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; INDIA |
172 |
AU |
: |
Catalani E |
TI |
: |
Review of the Indian market of anti-tuberculosis drugs
: focus on the utilisation of Rifampicin-based products |
SO |
: |
INT J TB & LUNG DIS 1999, 3 (Suppl), S289-291 |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
There is a need to better understand the extent
of the utilisation of Rifampicin in the market, particularly in
Fixed-Dose Combinations (FDC). The objective of the study was to
review the Indian market of anti-TB drugs, as this is the largest
single market in the world of this therapeutic class where about
50% of global consumption of Rifampicin takes place. The study was
designed to review and analyse the sales data proffered by the Indian
market audit. Estimated data relating to public sector product usage
were utilised in order to obtain a more complete scenario.
There are 3 Indian Rifampicin fermentation plants
with a total capacity of about 340 metric tons, supplying to the
demand of local market and export activities. It is estimated that
there was a total consumption of 250-275 metric tons of Rifampicin
in 1998. Other raw materials for the formulation of anti-TB drugs
such as Isoniazid, Pyrazinamide and Ethambutol are also produced
in India for local consumption as also for export. FDCs were particularly
produced in India with sales of about US$139 million in 1998 (public
sector - $60 million HMR/India estimate), private sector
- $70 million.
Sales for Lupin Laboratories represents 41% of
the private market followed by Novartis with a market share of 10%.
Rifampicin + INH FDC group is the largest of all anti-TB drug sub
groups. Exactly 50% of this market sub-group are represented by
the sales of two leading double FDC brand names worth US$25.8 million.
Triple FDC (Rifampicin + INH + Pyrazinamide) sales of US$10.4 million
are characterised by a large variety of different dosage ratios
for the 3 drugs and market leader has the market share of 14%. Two
quadruple FDCs sales in India are limited and the AKT FD brand has
87% of this sub-group for the time being. Both the public and private
sectors of anti-TB drugs are likely to grow in the future in volume
and value and the Indian pharmaceutical industry is very active
in the export of raw materials.
|
KEY WORDS : INDIAN MARKET; RIFAMPICIN; FIXED DOSE COMBINATION;
HEALTH ECONOMICS; ITALY. |
173 |
AU |
: |
Khatri GR & Frieden TR |
TI |
: |
The status and prospects of tuberculosis control in
India |
SO |
: |
INT J TB & LUNG DIS 2000, 4, 193-200 |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
Much of the global strategy for TB control was
established in India, but every year, there are an estimated 2 million
cases of TB. To describe the policies, initial results and lessons
learnt from implementation of a RNTCP using the principles of DOTS
is the objective of this study. The RNTCP was designed and implemented
starting in 1993. With funding from Government of India, State Governments,
the World Bank and bilateral donors, regular supply of drugs and
logistics was ensured. Persons with chest symptoms who attend health
facilities are referred to microscopy centres for diagnosis. Diagnosed
cases are categorized as per WHO guidelines and treatment is given
by direct observation. Systematic recording and cohort reporting
is done. From October 1993 through mid-1999, 146012 patients were
put on treatment in the programme. The quality of diagnosis was
improved, with the ratio of smear-positive to smear-negative patients
being maintained at 1:1. Case detection rates varied greatly between
project sites and correlated with the percentage of patients who
were smear-positive among those examined for diagnosis, suggesting
heterogeneous disease rates. Treatment success was achieved in 81%
of new smear-positive patients, 82% of new smear-negative patients,
89% of patients with extra-pulmonary TB and 70% of re-treatment
patients.
The RNTCP has successfully treated approximately
80% of patients in 20 districts of 15 states of India. Treatment
success rates are more than double and death rates are less than
a seventh those of the previous programme. Starting in late 1998,
the programme began to scale up and now covers more than 130 million
people. Maintaining the quality of implementation during the expansion
phase is the next challenge.
|
KEY WORDS: DOTS; HEALTH ECONOMICS; RNTCP; INDIA. |

RNTCP at Bangalore Mahanagara Palike Area |
174 |
AU |
: |
Chaulk CP, Friedman M & Dunning R |
TI |
: |
Modeling the epidemiology and economics of directly
observed therapy in Baltimore |
SO |
: |
INT J TB & LUNG DIS 2000, 4 , 201-207 |
DT |
: |
Per |
AB |
: |
From 1958 to 1978, Baltimore maintained one of
the highest pulmonary TB rates in the US. But, from 1978 to 1992
its TB rate declined by 64.3% and its ranking for TB fell from second
highest among large US cites to twenty-eighth. This TB trend coincided
with the implementation of an aggressive DOT programme by Baltimores
Health Department through city based DOTS, community outreach, home
based DOTS by public health nurses. By 1992, nearly 80% of Baltimore
patients were treated by DOTS.
Modeling is used to estimate the range of TB cases
prevented in Baltimore under DOT. Case estimates equal the difference
between the observed number of TB cases in Baltimore versus the
expected number if Baltimores TB trend was replaced by the
TB trend for the US (low estimate) or the TB trend for all US cities
with over 250000 residents (high estimate). Economic savings are
estimated.
It has been estimated that without DOT there would
have been between 1577 (53.6%) and 2233 (75.9%) more TB cases in
Baltimore, costing $18.8 million to $27.1 million. Cases prevented
and expenditures saved increased with increased DOT participation.
This model predicts that Baltimores TB decline
accompanying DOT resulted in health care savings equal to twice
the citys total TB control budget for this period. These results
are most plausibly due to DOT, since it was the only major change
in Baltimores TB control programme and rising TB risk factors
AIDS, injection drug use, poverty in a city where
TB had been epidemic should have triggered a TB increase as in comparable
US cities, rather than the observed decline. As national TB rates
continue to decline it will be important to identify ways to capture
and reinvest these savings to support effective TB control programmes.
|
KEY WORDS:; HEALTH ECONOMICS; USA. |
176 |
AU |
: |
Trebucq A |
TI |
: |
Requirements for anti tuberculosis drug tender requests |
SO |
: |
INT J TB & LUNG DIS 1999, 3 (Suppl), S358-S361 |
DT |
: |
|
AB |
: |
As more and more institutions and experts advocate
for the use of fixed-dose combinations (FDC) of anti-TB drugs, it
is expected that the market will change dramatically in the next
few years. Prices should go down, but quality must remain an essential
goal for managers in charge of the procurement process. In this
paper, general essential requirements for suppliers submitting for
competitive bidding are reviewed, in particular the WHO certification
scheme. The expiry of patents on older drugs, the diversification
of production sites and liberalization of the international pharmaceuticals
market has resulted in multi source generics. These are the only
affordable and alternative drugs for low income countries. The main
criteria while procuring drugs for the NTP should be price, quality
and availability of anti-TB drugs. As in case of other drugs bids
for anti-TB drugs should also take into account the specifications
such as delay and reliability of delivery. The standard steps in
the tender cycle are selection of suppliers to participate in the
tender selection and issue of contracts to winning bidders, and
monitoring of performance and product quality. The call for suppliers
can be made through open tender, restricted tender and direct procurement
from single supplier at the quoted price. There is an informal network
between authorities, international organizations and NGOs to facilitate
the selection of suppliers who qualify the requirements. For quality
assurance for drugs, same regulations like Good Manufacturing Practices
(GMP), Pharmaceutical product licence (PPL) and the WHO certification
scheme have been introduced from 1963 onwards in many developed
and developing countries. The WHO certification scheme is based
on voluntary participation of countries that import and export drugs
by way of three different certificates. (i) Statement of licensing
: it attests that a PPL has been issued by the regulatory authorities
of the exporting country for use by importing agents; (ii) Certificate
of a pharmaceutical product issued by the competent national regulatory
authorities of the exporting country; (iii) Batch certificate
the manufacturer issues this certificate for each individual batch
of a pharmaceutical product. It is a mandatory requirement and is
provided with the bidding documents. It attests the quality and
expiry date of a specific batch and should include the specifications
of the final product. The cost of FDCs are likely to go down and
would become accessible for the programme. For the NTP, different
combinations of specified formulations of three or four drug combinations
are recommended and can be made available on the basis of making
request for the type of combination and dosage for each product.
A contract taking into account of all the details of the drugs and
of the services (labeling, packaging, shelf life, expiry dates,
bid bonds, shipment specification, penalties for default) need to
be signed between the provider and purchaser. Quality control of
FDCs is essential. Bio-availability studies must be conducted for
rifampicin according to the protocol recommended by the IUALTD and
the WHO, whereas for other components dissolution tests are significant.
This should be made as condition before bidding or before supply.
Management of competitive tenders is an important and difficult
task. Low prices and high quality drugs must be the result of this
process in order to procure good drugs for TB patients.
|
KEY WORDS: HEALTH ECONOMICS; FIXED DOSE COMBINATION;
DRUG TENDERS; BIOAVAILABILITY; FRANCE. |
|
|